Call it what you will, incentives are what get people to work harder.
Nikita Khrushchev
Back in the good old days when the great unwashed could simply be shipped off to the colonies with nary a second thought, transportation of convicts was in the hands of private companies. These companies were compensated based on the number of prisoners shipped. As long as they were signed and sealed, no one cared over much if they were delivered and a depressing percentage of prisoners perished on-board these dreadful hulks. Eventually, the government, realising they were being short-changed and running the risk of running out of forced labourers, changed the metric from prisoners shipped to the number who arrived alive.
In the former Soviet Union, glass plant managers were rewarded according to tonnage of sheet glass they produced. Inevitably, plants churned out sheet glass so thick as to be useless. Right, thought the apparatchiks, we’ll sort out you bourgeois shirkers! And changed the rules so that square meterage of glass produced was rewarded instead. How did our put-upon factory managers respond? Yep, you guessed it; they produced glass so thin and fragile it would shatter as soon as you looked at it.
Often, our response to a perceived difficulty is offer incentives. Students misbehaving and not working hard enough? Vivo Miles! Teachers not working their fingers down to bloody bone? Performance Related Pay!
If no incentive is offered we’re in the terrifying position of simply relying on people’s desire to do the ‘right thing’. But, if people are properly incentivised, the reasoning goes, they will act with motivation, determination and efficiency. And generally speaking, most teachers do want to do the right thing. We’re nice like that. Rare indeed is the teacher that chooses education as a short cut to personal wealth. Although we want to adequately remunerated for our efforts, generally speaking we teach because we want to. There aren’t many teachers holding on to exciting new methods for teaching spelling or oxbow lakes until somebody offers to pay them a little bit more.
Inevitably, schools always want to take a little bit more. They exhort us to might works by sharing values and vision, but nothing beats the simplicity of carrot and stick. But as soon as an incentive is offered, people change. We tend, unerringly, to respond to incentives by doing what is in our best interests. We respond to the letter of the initiatives rather than their spirit; we ignore the intention and focus solely on the incentive.
Consider for instance the plight of pupils in receipt of the Pupil Premium. Of course it’s a wonderful thing that we should seek to narrow the attainment gap between the most disadvantaged and the most privileged. And it makes complete sense to scrutinise what all this public money is being spent on; we can’t have schools simply squandering it on whatever shiny baubles are offered for sale by the sharp suited consultant class. As ever, the DfE is unwilling to trust that schools will do the right thing and has let slip the attack dog of Ofsted. Schools are held to account for the gap between the achievement of their Pupil Premium students and everyone else. It’s not enough for your PPs to be doing better than the national average, or even, better than everyone else’s. You have to ensure there is no gap between different cohorts of students within your own school. And if you don’t? Simple: you require improvement, with all the Sisyphean toil this judgement will bring. This really does go on: read about some examples here.
Now, I hope no school would be so cynical but if the incentive is for schools to narrow the gap, the obvious solution is to reduce the attainment on non Pupil Premium students. Obviously no one would want this, and when I suggested the possibility to Mike Cladingbowl he looked suitably horrified, but this is logical, self-interested solution to a perverse incentive.
In his deceptively simple little book, The Art of Thinking Clearly: Better Thinking, Better Decisions, Rolf Dobrelli offers this advice: “Good incentive systems comprise both intent and reward.” Clearly this is sage advice, but how so to do?
When managing change, we tend to focus on problems. We look at what is preventing people from behaving in the way we want them to behave rather than focussing on those instances of success. In Switch: How to change things when change is hard, Chip and Dan Heath refer to these instances of success as ‘bright spots’, and they suggest that the best way to change behaviour is to focus on these positives instead of all the frustratingly negative, err, negatives.
Most people willingly tread the path of least resistance, so if we offer incentives that make it easy to replicate these successes, we might be more likely to see the changes we want.
Here’s a suggested process we could use to interrogate whether our incentive system is likely to do what we actually want:
- What is the behaviour you want to change, and how exactly do you want to change it? Be specific
- To what extent might this behaviour be caused by the situation rather than people? What can you change first?
- Incentives work best when they affect emotions. How do people feel now, and how do you want them to feel?
- What can you take away to ensure people are not too exhausted to make the desired change? Consciously opt out of old initiatives.
- What examples can you find of the behaviour you want to incentivise? Grow these bright spots.
- How could you use the anchoring effect to make this behaviour the new norm? How can you harness the power of inertia?
- Is your incentive working? How do you know? What unexpected changes have occurred?
Dobrelli suggests, “If a person’s or an organisation’s behaviour confounds you, ask yourself what incentive might lie behind it. I guarantee you’ll be able to explain 90% of the cases that way. What makes up the remaining 10%? Passion, idiocy, psychosis or malice.”
[…] Read more on The Learning Spy… […]
Interesting blog. I think one of the challenges is recognising that these “incentives” are not actually incentives at all. The incentives in education are never going to come from financial bonuses or promotion because the system does not work like that. As you say the vast majority of teachers are in it because they want young people to do as well as they possibly can. So if that is the carrot then by what means do you encourage teachers to be even more dedicated to that cause?
I am not sure that labelling a school as RI if the PP kids don’t all out perform the average (!) is what I would describe as an incentive. A threat perhaps?
Carrot and stick are both incentives, no?
Many of the incentives provided by the education system might be summed up as, Beatings will continue until morale improves”.
Interesting post. There is a huge amount more out there about this and related topics – and almost all of it is being ignored by the education sector in favour of the above.
Any examples you could share Ian?
Hmm, some of it probably not – a bit close to home in terms of my particular school to elaborate in a public place.
But in general the cognitive flaw(s) that lead people to assume that seniority = authority = correctness, the more senior you are the more likely you are to be ‘right’. Then if things don’t go according to plan, assuming that is because you did *too little* of your preferred strategy – or that the people who were supposed to be enacting it were incompetent.- rather than the fact that it might have been flawed in the first place. Or that people who had adopted alternative strategies were wrong simply because they were not doing what you expected.
All sorts of anecdotes of that large and small over the years. Up to and including unworkable teaching strategies.
Hopefully you’ll appreciate why I might not want to elaborate on some of this. However, try Margaret Heffernan’s book Wilful Blindness for a wider exposition on the matter. Likewise John Kay’s book Obliquity on why doing more of the bleeding obvious is not always the answer.
On reflection, that is rather an evasive answer, but I don’t feel it is appropriate to discuss the internal issues of a specific school in public.
However, one might observe that some of the more successful schools are intensely competitive. They are also find it (relatively) easy to recruit – that ‘outstanding’ label has an effect. As a result they can afford to take a more bullish attitude to their staff.
For instance if through ‘strong management’ you require people to be on message above all else, all it does is encourage people to be compliant rather than engaged, and you end up chasing out of people the self-motivation that they need to be good teachers in the first place. They are also less likely to speak up to highlight problems that mangement may not see.
To me that is pretty perverse.
You think? I see struggling schools as more likely to require compliance.
Believe me, I know. As I said, I don’t think it’s right to discuss specific schools in public, but don’t under-estimate the amount of pressure that can be put on people by a management that has the scent of Outstanding in its nostrils. Perhaps one of the untold stories of an over-zealous inspection regime?
[…] questions to guard against availability bias and made up data Perverse incentives and how to counter them A request: Have you experienced any craziness in your […]
I think you’re absolutely spot on about the importance of incentives, although I think the most perverse incentives are those schools give to low achieving pupils. A child who has GCSE targets of Ds or Es is being told ‘try your hardest and you’ll be worse than average’. It isn’t surprising that few of these children work hard when the ‘carrot’ on offer is proof of their inferiority.
[…] Perverse incentives and how to counter them […]